World Food Policy Volume/Issue 2-2/3-1 Fall 2015/Spring 2016 | Page 162

Food Security In an Age of Falling Commodity and Food Prices: The Case of Sub-Saharan Africa the existence of crop storage facilities, the percentage of food loss, and the existence of nutritional standards. Despite high economic growth rate, the numbers of poor people did not decrease in SSA, even if some components of the Human Development Index (UNDP 2015) and the index itself have known a modest improvement (0.518 in 2014 versus 0.499 in 2010). In this context, the impact of fallen food prices on food security is equivocal. The Uncertain Impacts of Fallen Food Prices on Food Security In low-income SSA countries, the urban poor are net food consumers, while small farmers are, generally, net sellers. Rising prices hurt consumers by reducing their purchasing power but benefit producers by increasing their profits. Rising food prices for basic staple food is not beneficial for Africa’s poor who consume more food than what they can produce, particularly poor families living in cities that spend the majority of their income on basic foodstuffs. Rising food prices are also having important macroeconomic impacts on many African countries since more food is being imported from the world market leading to worsening balances of trade (only 5% of Africa’s imports of cereals come from other African countries). Lower food prices relative to incomes benefit to food security, by making food acquisition more affordable especially to poor consumers. Food purchases typically account for a significant share of overall household income of the poor in SSA. Overall benefits would, however, be depending on whether households are net buyers of food. At the same time, lower prices also diminish producers’ returns. At the country level, low international food prices would also benefit those countries that rely to a large extent on imported food products, as long as their currencies do not decrease as to annihilate the gains from low prices. Consumers may benefit from the low prices of imported food in particular when these prices result from developed countries farm subsidies. But this situation is largely hazardous as the recent price surge demonstrates, while at the same time small farmers face enormous difficulties in trying to expand production in response to higher prices. Falling prices may impact on farmers’ profitability, reducing investments, and increasing unsustainable agricultural practices. Low returns could reduce incentives for larger investment in agriculture (rural infrastructure, credit availability, input services, research, and extension). As it was explained earlier, underinvestment in agriculture has been considered as one of the main structural causes for the sharp price increases of 2007–2008. Finally, lower food prices have intensively contributed to reduce (or even partially destroy) domestic agricultural activities. SSA experimented shrinkage of some agricultural sectors due to imports surges generated by low subsidized imports prices: the case of European products (for instance European poultry). Founded on a list of “‘infant industry” argument, a domestic development process in agriculture in SSA is extremely difficult to implement under the competition of largely subsidized imported products. 162