World Food Policy Volume/Issue 2-2/3-1 Fall 2015/Spring 2016 | Page 147

World Food Policy to be the smaller the higher the level of income, largely due to Engel’s law and the resulting lower share of income spent on food among richer households. Among the countries included here, Vietnam is again the only exception: an increase of food prices is welfare improving for all income quintiles in Vietnam. The conclusion from all this is that high food prices tend to hurt most developing countries and most individual households in that part of the world.7 How Should Policies Respond? G iven that high food prices cause harm to consumers, and the more so the lower the family income is, it is not a good idea for developing country governments to engage in policies, be it domestically or at the border, that support prices of agricultural products at a higher level than the market would generate. While this statement sounds nearly trivial, governments of several developing countries have a tendency to disregard it, placing more weight on the impact of prices on agricultural producers. In many cases this appears to be the case based on the notion that higher prices (and subsidies, be it on inputs or output) provide incentives for farmers to expand output, raising the availability of food on the market. The fact that high prices at the same time make it more difficult for consumers to have access to food appears to be discounted in the process of political decision making. Given that in many developing countries (and in the group of developing countries overall), the volume of food consumption is larger than that of food production, and hence that high prices do more harm than good, there should be more awareness of the negative implication of high-price policies. However, there are indications that the level of support provided to farmers in developing countries, including support through price raising policies, is on the rise. The measure used in the OECD to quantify the level of support provided by governments is the producer support estimate (PSE). In its percentage version, this indicator expresses the share of total farm revenue that comes from government policies as opposed to markets. As can be seen in Figure 13, in the rich countries, i.e., in the OECD area, this was at the level of around 30%–35% in the mid-1990s and declined to ~20% more recently. If we set against that a number of selected emerging economies we can see that the level of support they are providing to their agriculture has increased quite a bit in recent years and a good part of that is indeed price support. Among the overall group of countries covered in this analysis, the share of farm 7 This conclusion is obviously derived from a purely static argument. In a dynamic analysis, rising food prices can trigger income growth among food producers and rural workers. Where this results in a shift from net food buyer to net food producer status, rising food prices can have positive welfare implications for the households concerned. However, it will take some time for this effect to dominate. For a more extensive discussion and references to relevant literature, se Filipski and Covarrubias (2012). 147