The Maritime Economist Magazine Spring 2015 | Page 22

THEMARITIME Economist INPLAIN Policy makers’ choices and trade-offs Over the last decades, trade has grown faster than the economy as a whole, and shipping will continue to be the most important mode of transport with the lowest environmental impact. The long term perspectives for seaborne trade and the maritime businesses are good. Policy makers are well advised to identify and invest in maritime sectors where their countries may have a comparative advantage. And sometimes choices will have to be made. The following three examples illustrate such choices and possible trade-offs. Example #1: Would policy makers favor the national ship owners or rather the national seafarers? For a national ship owner to remain competitive, he may want to employ less costly foreign seafarer. To be allowed to do so, he may need to register his ship under a foreign flag. Without the emergence of open registries – most were initially set up in developing countries – the ship owners of the traditional, richer, maritime nations may not have remained in business. The flags of Liberia, Marshall Islands and Panama were first and foremost used by ship owners from the United States, Europe and Japan. “ Policy makers are wellinadvised to identify and invest The implementation of the Taman port project will facilitate the process of maritime sectors where their diversion ofmay have a out of countries Russian cargo Ukrainian ports. comparative advantage. ME Mag Example #2: Is the priority the shipper, i.e. the importer and exporter, or rather the service provider? In several countries, still today liner shipping companies are allowed to engage in so-called “conferences”, which may include the joint setting of freight rates. Shippers generally consider that such price fixing is detrimental to their interests, while shipping companies argue that this helps them to 22 provide better services at a more stable freight rate. In the European Union, the “anti-trust immunity” of liner shipping conferences was significantly weakened with a view to increasing competition and reducing freight rates. Example #3: Are policy makers more concerned about the nationally flagged fleet or about the attractiveness of their national seaports? In many countries, maritime cabotage (i.e. shipping between two national seaports) is still reserved to nationally flagged ships. This protects the national shipowners and seafarers who are employed on nationally flagged ships. It may even help to generate business for national ship yards, if the legislation includes the obligation to deploy nationally build vessels on cabotage services. At the same time, such limitations put national ports at a disadvantage when competing for transshipment services. In Malaysia, cabotage restrictions were softened in order to help national seaports compete better with Singapore for transshipment from and to other Malaysian ports. In conclusion, it is no longer a policy choice to support “the” maritime sector, but the challenge is to identify and support selected maritime businesses. Policy makers need to carefully assess 1) the competitive environment for each of the maritime sectors individually it wishes to develop; 2) the value added of a sector for the country’s economy including possible spill-over effects to other sectors - maritime or not; 3) assess existing and potential synergies between maritime businesses; and 4) design industrial policies to support the businesses the country wishes to develop. Further reading: The article makes use of the latest available data, including for example world fleet dat