MAL 28:19 MAL28 | Page 52

COVER STORY Brand Building And Innovating In An Irrational World By Andrew Riungu F or the past two years or so, I have been fascinated with Behavioral Economics as a framework to demystifying and better understanding human behavior. This is not to say that I stumbled upon BE, as it is commonly known, two years ago. My first interactions with BE was probably about six years ago, but back then it was still relatively new and the chief evangelists were those in academia. For those of you who may not be familiar with the term, Behavioral Economics is part of the social sciences and seeks to understand how people make decisions. If you would like an academic description of Behavioral Economics, we would refer to it as systematic irrational behavior associated with decision-making. Why irrational and not rational systematic behavior? Well, this is the essence of BE which seeks to improve on traditional economics or economic theory. Humans on the other hand, do not think like econs, especial- ly for frequent purchases. For brands that intend to sell to the same customer time-and- time again, transactional util- ity is the default setting for your customers. It is impera- tive for such brands to ensure that they are driving positive transactional utility on as many occasions as possible. 50 MAL28/19 ISSUE Behavioral Economics is part of the social sciences and seeks to understand how people make decisions. If you would like an academic description of Behavioral Economics, we would refer to it as systematic irrational behavior associated with decision-making. Traditional economics, founded on the premise that all human beings are rational and make rational choices about everything, is used to create optimization models to mitigate against the occasional error in judgement that humans make. These errors are what we call biases and heuristics - heuristics is just a fancy term for a mental shortcut or a rule of thumb. Founding fathers of BE like Daniel Kahneman & Amos Tversky successfully dispelled this notion that humans are fully rational by showcasing that in fact, a significant majority of our decisions are based on irrationality. For more information on how Kahneman dispelled this notion, I suggest reading Daniel Kahneman’s bestseller book, Thinking Fast & Slow. Allow me to share a brief synopsis of what Kahneman (with help from Tversky) talks about in his book. Our decision making process is dictated by two systems; system 1 and system 2. System 1 is fast and intuitive, derived from the reptilian part of the brain that deals primarily with instinct. System 2 on the other hand is slow and laborious, using more of logic rather than instinct. In short, system 1 is irrational and system 2 is rational. Humans get by based on irrational behavior that is punctuated with a series of biases (both conscious and unconscious) and rules of thumb, to allow If humans feel the price paid for a certain product, service or experience is exces- sive or a rip off, they experience negative transactional utility. This negative trans- actional utility, more often than not, puts the customer on a path to “seek justice” by informing people of how they were robbed. us to save brain energy to focus on tasks that will require more brain power, like studying for an exam or picking the right mortgage plan. In short, as humans, we have not evolved this far based on rational decisions - irrationality is what got us this far, and will continue to take us farther. When it comes to brand building and innovation, this systematic irrational behavior needs firm understanding in order for it to be considered across all stages of the brand building and innovation process. One such important aspect that is crucial to brand building and innovation is utility - happiness or satisfaction. Utility (or happiness) stems from our irrational behavior... the happiness or satisfaction we derive from an innovation, a brands product or service, does not originate from a rational point of view, but from an irrational point of view. There are two broad types of utility that consumers can derive from a new innovation or an existing brands offering; Acquisition utility: This is the happiness/ satisfaction one gets from perceived benefit of the product, service or experience after acquiring the service, product or experience. For example: you decide to buy a watch that you feel will speak to your sense of style and make you feel good… heck it could even help uplift your mood every time you look at it. Less focus is placed on the cost - the benefit outweighs the cost. Transactional utility: This is the happiness/ satisfaction one gets from the terms of the transaction, regardless of the perceived benefit. For example: when buying a drink , you will expect the price to be “fair” but you make variations to your acceptable price based on where you are purchasing the drink from. If you are at a high-end restaurant, you will reluctantly accept a higher cost because of the venue where the transaction is taking place. Your reluctance to pay the “exorbitant” price will leave a bad taste in your mouth and this will in turn lead to you having a negative transactional utility for that restaurant. This negative transactional utility will even be higher if the same “exorbitant” cost is charged at your local grocery store. You will only experience positive transactional utility if the terms of the transaction are “fair”. To put it bluntly, if the price is within the realms of the reference price of the product, service or experience in question, you are likely to experience positive transactional utility. Traditional economics and economic theory advocates that all humans experience/pursue acquisition utility. Economists do not experience transactional utility because to them, the terms of the transaction are a Supposedly Irrelevant Factor (SIF). This notion is based on the thinking that humans think rationally and are able to overlook “irrelevant” details like price if they have a job that needs to be done by a particular product or service. To an econ, if the perceived benefit is not a strong enough driving force, then you should not be considering the product or service. This does not mean that econs are immune to bargains… bargains are welcome but merely seen as an added bonus in their pursuit for acquisition utility. Humans on the other hand, do not think like econs, especially for frequent