International Journal on Criminology Volume 4, Number 2, Winter 2016 | Page 115

Mafia: From the Use of Violence to Artificial Scarcity In practical terms, the Mafia monitors the access to resources and to goods finished in the territories over which it has sovereignty. This allows it to discriminate between non-Mafiosi and Mafiosi by limiting access by the former. It even carries out further discrimination between non-Mafiosi to reward (or punish) certain behaviors which are more or less cooperative or, more generally, to encourage non-Mafiosi to adopt non-hostile and even subservient behavior. Artificial scarcity affects a wide variety of areas in the daily lives of consumers and producers. For example, obtaining a place in a day nursery or retirement home in Mafia territory is mediated by the criminal organization. It is not the Mafia which creates these places but it manages to set itself up as an intermediary facilitating access to the resource for whoever is requesting it. In return, the beneficiary of the Mafia “favor” becomes de facto indebted and thus puts himself—albeit involuntarily—in a situation of dependency vis-à-vis the Mafia. The same system is set up on a larger scale at the production level. The most sophisticated version of artificial scarcity in this context consists in the Mafia’s infiltration of key sectors of the legal economy. In order to achieve this, the Mafia controls legal enterprises whose activity is declared and visible, taking care to choose sectors which will allow them to condition a whole network. For example, Italian Mafias are especially present in the building and public works sector. Within this sector, the Mafia more specifically targets concrete production and clearing/ earthmoving activities. These activities have the characteristic of being upstream in the procedures involved in building and public works, and of being territorially embedded. Pouring concrete and supplying machines are necessarily extremely localized activities. Not delivering the concrete, or delivering it late, means wielding real power to obstruct work on the building site and to damage clients further down the line. It is the same if, in the end, the clearing/earthmoving machines are not available at the right time. Mafiosi thus have the power to block a building site or cause production to be late, which entails a considerable cost. Controlling these key activities therefore allows the Mafia to condition the whole of the building and public works sector, to impose its own suppliers and dictate its conditions. The Chinese Triads, on the other hand, have control over the soya bean market so that they can condition the Asian catering/restaurant sector. Artificial scarcity is based on—and, conversely, causes—a fundamental asymmetry between Mafiosi and non-Mafiosi: on the one hand, Mafiosi benefit from strong cohesiveness (the famous “force of the associative tie” defining the Mafia according to article 416-bis of the Italian Penal Code); while, on the other hand, non-Mafiosi are largely unorganized, not structured within an association and therefore in a position of weakness vis-à-vis Mafiosi and the scarcity which they create. Thanks to artificial scarcity, the Mafiosi accentuate this asymmetry by putting possible opponents in an economically vulnerable position, while favoring access to resources for those who cooperate. This is how Mafia power takes hold and becomes widely accepted; it no longer needs to resort to regular violence in order to impose its rules. 114