Financial History Issue 132 (Winter 2020) | Page 19

South Sea Bubble from mid−1719 to end of 1720 South Sea Stock startups x10 Sea Sea venture capitalists or, even more, to general “blind pools”? Such investors do not find out “full particulars” of what is done with their money for quite a while. Just how much was this £2,000 that the “great man” of the Mackay version of the story is supposed to have made? Based on GDP per capita, which grew by about 1,000 over the last three centuries, the gains reaped by the projector are compa- rable to about £2 million, or $2 million today. That is not shabby. But it pales when compared to the sums collected by pro- moters of the innumerable ICOs (initial coin offerings) in the last few years. Various observers have doubted the literal truth of the anecdote, and some details in the Oldmixon/Mackay narrative are simply not consistent with how new ventures were set up in 1720. The most plausible scenario is that this story is an amalgam and embel- lishment of several actual occurrences, an account that is “too good not to be true.” But it is only a slight embellishment. Old- mixon’s version of this story concluded with an observation about the irrational behavior that crowd psychology lures investors into. He wrote that, “What, at another time, when people were in their senses, and knew what to do with their money, would have occa- sional a hue and cry after the cheat, was then only a matter of laughter, and the crime and the sum hardly thought worth taking notice of.” And that seems very accurate, as specula- tive excitement does warp people’s percep- tion of what is sensible. It did so in 1720, and does so today. Before considering projects from the 1720 era that may have contributed to the creation of the anecdote, let us say a few words on the background of the South Sea Bubble. There is much publicly available material on this historical event online. A short overview is available in a chapter in Edward Chancellor’s book, Devil Take the Hindmost. The main book-length recent treatment is in John Carswell’s The South Sea Bubble. This episode of extreme inves- tor excitement had huge financial flows centered on the South Sea Company. Fig- ure 1 shows the price of its main security. The South Sea Bubble was largely inspired by John Law’s Mississippi Scheme in Paris, which reached its peak at the end of 1719. Both the French and the British manias were enabled by the return to relative peace and tranquility after several prolonged and debilitat- ing wars. Interest rates were dropping, 1719.5 1720 1720.5 1721 year Year Figure 1. South Sea stock price and the number of new projects announced in London each month from July 1719 to December 1720. The scatter plot shows 10 times the number of start-ups each month, so that the one for June 1720 corresponds to the 88 ventures that, according to one count, were announced that month. and investors’ “animal spirits” were stirring. The ebullient atmosphere of 1719 offered new opportunities to promoters, and they began soliciting money from investors. Figure 1 shows, in the scatter plot, the number of new projects announced each month, but multiplied by 10, so that the 88 projects of June 1720 correspond to 880 in the figure. These numbers are taken from William Scott’s The Constitution and Finance of English, Scottish and Irish Joint-stock Companies to 1720. As can be seen, out of the almost 200 projects that Scott tabulated, only 13 were started in 1719. But they were noticed by many observers. Also noticed was what seemed to many skeptics to be the inordinate credulity of the public that was eager to get involved. This led to the first of the events that likely inspired the “under- taking of great advantage, but nobody to know what it is” fable. Starting on Friday, December 18, 1719, the Daily Post carried for sev- eral days an ad for an “extraordinary scheme for a new insurance company to be proposed, (whereof publick notice will speedily be given in this paper),” with “permits to subscribe” offered for £0.05 each. No names of projectors, nor details of the scheme were cited. The sale of the “permits” took place on Thursday, December 24. Two days later, this same paper had an ad which offered refunds for the “several hundred” of those permits that had been sold and explained that the whole thing was a hoax designed to show how easy it was to “impose upon a credulous multitude.” The ad mentioned that the person who had collected the money was unknown to anyone in the crowd, and signed receipts with a name made up from the initials of the six people who concocted the scheme. While this spoof did show that British investors were “a credulous multitude,” it was far less extreme than the Oldmixon/ Mackay fable. Even if all 1,000 permits were sold, the total take was only £50, not the £2,000 of the fable. Furthermore, for an individual buying a single permit, the price of £0.05 was only the cost of a dozen cups of coffee. So the “credulous multitude” were not risking very much individually. Furthermore, they were not putting their money into an “undertaking …nobody to know what it is,” but into an insur- ance scheme. Actuarial science was in its infancy, so insurance was underdeveloped, www.MoAF.org  |  Winter 2020  |  FINANCIAL HISTORY  17