European Policy Analysis Volume 2, Number 1, Spring 2016 | Page 61

European Policy Analysis 5. Conclusion default solutions and electronic platforms) and this way encourage more consumers to buy a PPP. This would be beneficial for reducing distribution costs and reaching the critical mass that is needed for providers to offer cost effective products and reach economies of scale. (EIOPA 2014b, Paragraph 269). A close reading of the growing body of primary sources on a more integrated common market for private pension products reveals major divisions between the European Commission and certain large providers, on the one hand, and several member states as well as smaller suppliers that are more attuned to the existing particularities of national markets on the other. EIOPA as a pan-European regulatory body charged with the wider task of hedging systemic risk in the occupational and private pension sectors finds itself in a rather delicate dilemma. The Commission insistently expects it to devise a 2nd tier regulation embodied in a standardized PPP that ought to be attractive for all EU citizens. Yet, this endeavor runs the risk of unsettling the balance between the pillars of the 28 distinct national retirement provision policies, and it is hardly conceivable without far-reaching tax harmonization for which neither EIOPA nor the Commission have the necessary competence, albeit the latter’s DG GROW clearly harbors a sustained ambition. While resistance against tax harmonization remains strong, a prolonged phase of closeto-zero real interest rates might present a window of opportunity, since nonexistent profits render no revenue no matter what the tax rate is. This pattern clearly speaks to our theoretical assumptions about crisis policymaking. The fact that the Commission repeatedly urges EIOPA to generate far-reaching policy advice is in line with the expectation that experts and interest groups have considerable influence on policymaking when the complex Strikingly, EIOPA even claims that while usually PPPs should not be bought without “the benefit of independent professional advice” (EIOPA 2014b,Paragraph 490), this were not the case in the 2nd regime. Here, EIOPA trusts and advises the public to trust solely in its own “generic advice suitable for the vast majority of citizens that could be disseminated through government or public agencies” (EIOPA 2014b, Paragraph 490). Thus, while a number of details remain very cloudy, EIOPA counsels the Commission—in a very idiosyncratic reading of the stakeholder feedback it received—to use the cover of consumer protection to pre-emptively depoliticize pension policies and to channel a potentially huge segment of the market for PPPs to a limited range of large providers that are likely to be able to comply with EIOPA’s regulatory demands (that are sketched in Paragraphs 271–292 of EIOPA 2014b). Furthermore, EIOPA strives to monopolize the advice citizens receive on PPP investment decisions. It is remarkable that an initiative with such far-reaching distributional consequences for both consumers and providers of PPPs and of member states’ pension policies in general have so far received hardly any public or academic attention. 61